27.2 – Explicit and Implicit Costs, and Accounting and Economic Profit
Learning Objectives
- Explain the difference between explicit costs and implicit costs
- Understand the relationship between cost and revenue
Private enterprise, the ownership of businesses by private individuals, is a hallmark of the U.S. economy. When people think of businesses, often giants like Wal-Mart, Microsoft, or General Motors come to mind. But firms come in all sizes, as shown in Table 1. The vast majority of American firms have fewer than 20 employees. As of 2020, the U.S. Census Bureau counted 6.1 million firms with employees in the U.S. economy. Slightly less than half of all the workers in private firms are at the 21,000 large firms, meaning they employ more than 500 workers. Another 32% of workers in the U.S. economy are at firms with fewer than 100 workers. These small-scale businesses include everything from dentists and lawyers to businesses that mow lawns or clean houses. Indeed, Table 1 does not include a separate category for the millions of small “non-employer” businesses where a single owner or a few partners are not officially paid wages or a salary, but simply receive whatever they can earn.
Number of Employees | Firms (% of total) | Number of Employees | Annual Payroll |
---|---|---|---|
Total | 6,140,612 | 134.2 million | $7,565 billion |
0-4 | 3,828,482 (62.3%) | 6.0 million (4.5%) | $295 billion (3.9%) |
5–9 | 1,004,591 (16.4%) | 6.6 million (4.9%) | $265 billion (3.5%) |
10–19 | 638,663 (10.4%) | 8.6 million (6.4%) | $353 billion (4.7%) |
20–99 | 552,921 (9.0%) | 21.7 million (16.2%) | $979 billion (12.9%) |
100–499 | 95,000 (1.5%) | 18.7 million (13.9%) | $1,016 billion (13.4%) |
500 or more | 20,955 (0.3%) | 72.6 million (54.1%) | $4,657 billion (61.6%) |
(Source: U.S. Census, 2020 SUSB Annual Data Tables by Establishment Industry (census.gov)) |
Each of these businesses, regardless of size or complexity, tries to earn a profit:
[latex]\text{Profit}=\text{Total Revenue}-\text{Total Cost}[/latex]
Total revenue is the income brought into the firm from selling its products. It is calculated by multiplying the price of the product times the quantity of output sold:
[latex]\text{Total Revenue}=\text{Price}\times\text{Quantity}[/latex]
We will see in the following chapters that revenue is a function of the demand for the firm’s products.
Orthodox economists distinguish between two types of cost: explicit and implicit. Explicit costs are out-of-pocket costs, that is, payments that are actually made. Wages that a firm pays its employees or rent that a firm pays for its office are explicit costs. Implicit costs are more subtle, but just as important. They represent the opportunity cost of using resources already owned by the firm. Often for small businesses, they are resources contributed by the owners; for example, working in the business while not getting a formal salary, or using the ground floor of a home as a retail store.
These two definitions of cost are important for distinguishing between two conceptions of profit, accounting profit and economic profit. Accounting profit is a cash concept. It means total revenue minus explicit costs—the difference between dollars brought in and dollars paid out. Economic profit is total revenue minus total cost, including both explicit and implicit costs. The difference is important because even though a business pays income taxes based on its accounting profit, whether or not it is economically successful depends on its economic profit.
Calculating Implicit Costs
Consider the following example. Fred currently works for a corporate law firm. He is considering opening his own legal practice, where he expects to earn $200,000 per year once he gets established. To run his own firm, he would need an office and a law clerk. He has found the perfect office, which rents for $50,000 per year. A law clerk could be hired for $35,000 per year. If these figures are accurate, would Fred’s legal practice be profitable?
Step 1. First you have to calculate the costs. You can take what you know about explicit costs and total them:
[latex]\begin{array}{lr}Office\;rental:\; & \$50,000 \\ Law\;clerk's\;salary:\; & +\$35,000 \\ \hline Total\;explicit\;costs:\; &\$85,000 \end{array}[/latex]
Step 2. Subtracting the explicit costs from the revenue gives you the accounting profit.
[latex]\begin{array}{lr}Revenues:\; & \$200,000 \\ Explicit\;costs:\; & -\$85,000 \\ \hline Accounting\;profit:\; & \$115,000 \end{array}[/latex]
But these calculations consider only the explicit costs. To open his own practice, Fred would have to quit his current job, where he is earning an annual salary of $125,000. This would be an implicit cost of opening his own firm.
Step 3. You need to subtract both the explicit and implicit costs to determine the true economic profit:
[latex]\begin{array}{rcl}\text{Economic profit} & = & \text{total revenues} - \text{explicit costs} - \text{implicit costs} \\ & = & \$200,000 - \$85,000 - \$125,000 \\ & = & -\$10,000 \text{ per year}\end{array}[/latex]
Fred would be losing $10,000 per year. That does not mean he would not want to open his own business, but it does mean he would be earning $10,000 less than if he worked for the corporate firm.
Implicit costs can include other things as well. Maybe Fred values his leisure time, and starting his own firm would require him to put in more hours than at the corporate firm. In this case, the lost leisure would also be an implicit cost that would subtract from economic profits.
Now that we have an idea about the different types of costs, let’s look at cost structures. A firm’s cost structure in the long run may be different from that in the short run. We turn to that distinction in the next section.
Summary
Privately owned firms are motivated to earn profits. Profit is the difference between revenues and costs. While accounting profit considers only explicit costs, economic profit considers both explicit and implicit costs.
References
2020 U.S. Census. www.census.gov.
Glossary
- accounting profit
- total revenues minus explicit costs, including depreciation
- economic profit
- total revenues minus total costs (explicit plus implicit costs)
- explicit costs
- out-of-pocket costs for a firm, for example, payments for wages and salaries, rent, or materials
- firm
- an organization that combines inputs of labor, capital, land, and raw or finished component materials to produce and sell outputs for a profit
- implicit costs
- opportunity cost of resources already owned by the firm and used in business, for example, expanding a factory onto land already owned
- private enterprise
- the ownership of businesses by private individuals
- production
- the process of combining inputs to produce outputs, ideally of a value greater than the value of the inputs
- revenue
- income from selling a firm’s product; defined as price times quantity sold
system where the means of production (resources and businesses) are owned and operated by private individuals or groups of private individuals
an organization that combines inputs of labor, capital, land, and raw or finished component materials to produce and sell outputs for a profit
the income brought into the firm from selling its products
out-of-pocket costs for a firm, for example, payments for wages and salaries, rent, or materials
opportunity cost of resources already owned by the firm and used in business, for example, expanding a factory onto land already owned
total revenues minus explicit costs, including depreciation
total revenues minus total costs (explicit plus implicit costs)